My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
PL PACKET 05171983 (2)
StAnthony
>
Parks & Planning Commission
>
Planning Commission Packets
>
1983
>
PL PACKET 05171983 (2)
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
12/30/2015 3:30:25 PM
Creation date
12/30/2015 3:30:17 PM
Metadata
Fields
SP Box #
15
SP Folder Name
PL PACKETS 1983
SP Name
PL PACKET 05171983
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
59
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
View images
View plain text
144 The Practice of Local Gor,ernrr'tent Planning ~ <br /> i <br /> ments may have some force.However, when_independent governmental units I <br /> are constructing facilities, the advice is usually only advisory. <br /> Annexation At the urban fringe, newly developing areas seek to be annexed to <br /> a municipality so as to save on certain urban services, such as police protection, <br /> fire protection,and public utilities. A few states;such as Illinois, permit the exe- <br /> cution of annexation agreements whereby local governments and private devel- <br /> opers may negotiate as to public facility improvement costs. Even in states <br /> without such enabling laws, governments frequently have exercised such nego- <br /> tiating powers because of their strong bargaining position. Again, the issue here <br /> is the shifts and balances between private and public expenditures for capital <br /> facilities. <br /> Official maps Several states have provisions whereby local government can <br /> adopt official map ordinances. These ordinances permit local governments to <br /> specify the location of particular improvements—such as future park sites or <br /> the right-of-way for a future street—on a map.The designation of such a site on <br /> the official map puts private property owners on notice of a governments <br /> intention to construct a public facility. Placement of land within such an area <br /> may permit governments to deny zoning and building permits so that the even- <br /> tual cost of acquisition may not become prohibitive. However,there is usually a <br /> strict time limit(between one and three years)by the end of which a public body <br /> must purchase or condemn the land. <br /> Cost–revenue studies as a management tool' <br /> • Up to this point the emphasis in this chapter has been on public revenue and <br /> cost issues, relating to planning,that focus on citywide policy issues. Sources of <br /> revenue, intergovernmental aid. the budgeting function, and capital improve- <br /> ments programming tend to be comprehensive views that relate to fundamental <br /> broad policy issues. This section deals with the public revenue and cost factors <br /> involved when government is regulating new development or redevelopment. <br /> These techniques are used to help analyze or manage a particular development <br /> at a specific time and place. <br /> The concept of comparing public costs and revenues of a particular develop- <br /> ment proposal had its modern roots in the planning field in the late 1930s. The <br /> 1920s had seen a large amount of subdividing of properties into residential <br /> neighborhoods that were "premature" in that they remained forever vacant. A <br /> number of communities were trying to renew these "dead" subdivisions and <br /> would prepare simple analyses that showed how much more money would flow <br /> into the city treasury if the land were developed with improvements instead of <br /> remaining tax delinquent. <br /> Beginning in the late 1940s and the 1950s cost–revenue concepts were used in <br /> both central city and suburban planning situations.In the central city context <br /> urban renewal project.reports would frequently contain estimates showing how <br /> little tax revenue was now being generated by a'deteriorated neighborhood and <br /> how much it cost to service that neighborhood; these reports would then com- <br /> pare revenues and expenditures of the area after renewal. <br /> In the suburban context the 1950s was a time of:aggressive annexation in <br /> many communities. Because planning agencies did not control the precise loca- <br /> tion of urban development,they had to take annexation requests from wherever <br /> they came and in whatever location. The cost of extending major sewer and <br /> water lines and serving new populations encouraged planners and public admin- <br /> istrators to study the costs and revenues of annexing a particular area. <br /> By the late 1960s and early 1970s the focus of cost–revenue studies shifted to <br /> the problem of growth management. This came about through a combination of <br /> factors: inflation and the resulting increasing public costs for all services; a <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.