My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
07-12-2000 Council Agenda
>
City Council Packets
>
2000-2009
>
2000
>
07-12-2000 Council Agenda
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
6/26/2012 2:50:27 PM
Creation date
6/26/2012 2:48:51 PM
Metadata
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
38
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
View images
View plain text
Five of the programs are for youth not involved in the criminal justice system. These programs <br />typically try to affect several behaviors —for example, teen pregnancy, substance abuse, and <br />academic performance —in addition to preventing future criminal activity. Although society and <br />taxpayers can benefit in many ways from reductions in these other behaviors, at present the <br />Institute's analysis is restricted to measuring crime- related costs. <br />The remaining 11 programs are for youth already involved in the juvenile court system. Some <br />are for first- or second -time juvenile offenders while others are for chronic or serious offenders. <br />Usually the primary goal of these offender -based programs is to reduce the chance that a <br />juvenile will commit subsequent criminal offenses. <br />Analyzing the comparative economics of these programs requires interpretation beyond the <br />reported research results. Because most studies do not analyze program economics, the <br />Institute takes five analytical steps in reviewing each program. Table 2 displays the results. <br />(A forthcoming Institute report will describe the technical detail behind these estimates.) <br />1. How could a particular program be applied in Washington? For each intervention, <br />the Institute estimates the most likely practical application within the state's justice or early <br />intervention systems. For example, most of the juvenile offender programs listed on Tables <br />1 and 2 could be implemented in Washington through the juvenile courts. <br />2. Can a program produce the same results in another setting? Many programs have <br />demonstrated results in small experimental settings. Their success rates, however, may not <br />hold when they are replicated, especially on a larger scale. Rather than assuming that the <br />results achieved in one setting are always transferable, the Institute considers each program <br />individually, analyzing factors such as the strength of the research design, the length of the <br />follow -up period, and the size the of experiment. This process generally results in reduced <br />estimates of the expected effects for each intervention. <br />3. How much does a program cost? The Institute estimates the costs to taxpayers to <br />implement each program. <br />4. What is the value of a program's crime reduction for the state? If a program <br />succeeds in lowering crime rates, some costs of crime can be avoided in the future. The <br />Institute analyzes these life -cycle costs for the criminal justice system, estimating the <br />marginal operating and capital costs of police, courts and prosecutors, local govemment <br />juvenile and adult corrections' costs, and state govemment costs for the Juvenile <br />Rehabilitation Administration and the Department of Corrections. The Institute uses <br />national estimates to measure the monetary costs incurred by the direct victims of crime. If <br />an intervention can lower the amount of future crime, it can lower crime victim costs in <br />addition to criminal justice system costs paid by the taxpayer.5 <br />5. What are the summary economic statistics for a program? Combining all of this <br />information allows the calculation of standard economic measures. In Table 2 we show the <br />net present value of each program from a taxpayer's perspective, and from a combined <br />perspective of taxpayers and crime victims. We also show two other statistics: the number of <br />years it takes for a taxpayer to be "paid back" for the up -front cost of the program, and the <br />minimum percentage reduction in felonies the program needs to achieve to break even. <br />s See, Victim Costs and Consequences: A New Look, U.S. Dept. of Justice, 1996. Monetary Couhof- pocket's victim costs per felony <br />crime include estimated medical spending, mental health payments, lost future eamings, and property damage. <br />Page 32 <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.