Laserfiche WebLink
• <br />Gordon Heitke <br />January 28, 2008 <br />Page 9 of 13 <br />This subdivision also states that the rules for counting signatures under Section 8.04, <br />subd. 4 apply to preferences under Section 8.07. Section 8.04, subd. 4, clause (3) directs <br />that where a lot has multiple owners, only one signature will count (so the ambiguities <br />discussed under that section carry over into this section). However, Section 8.07 <br />subdivision 2 states that if multiple owners of a lot indicate different preferences, no <br />preferences shall be counted for that lot. These two provisions seem contradictory. It is <br />true that two owners might disagree and file conflicting preferences, and a question then <br />arises about which one to "count." But simply discarding the votes from that lot seems <br />likely to invite challenge. There might be other solutions, but this problem underscores <br />the practical and legal challenges imposed by the "owner preference" voting system <br />(which, to my knowledge, has no precedent in the State of Minnesota). <br />Finally, the preference system is essentially an election, but one without rules regarding <br />the form of the "ballot," the time and place of filing, canvassing of votes, and similar <br />issues. Municipal elections are governed by a large body of statues and rules, designed to <br />address the myriad of problems and disputes that arise in the course of a complex <br />process. The Commission Amendment creates a new election system, without the <br />supporting legal or administrative "infrastructure." As such, the system is likely to <br />generate high legal and administrative costs. <br />Subdivision 3. This subdivision creates a special rule for utilities in cases where <br />"property owners prefer an alternative which results in a street being improved without <br />utilities recommended by staff." In that situation, utilities may not be undertaken in that <br />street within five years after completion of the street unless the utilities and any related <br />street repair are financed without general revenue. Apparently, the intent of this <br />provision is to encourage owners to vote for the most cost- effective improvement, i.e. <br />street improvements that include utilities (at least where that combination is <br />recommended by staff). <br />However, the language leaves many open questions. When are utilities "recommended <br />by staff?" Who constitutes staff? Does the term include consulting engineers? What <br />evidence of a staff recommendation is needed? Would one sentence in a staff memo <br />suffice? If the feasibility study includes an option of streets without utilities (as it must, <br />under Section 8.05, subdivision 2), and the study concludes that such street -only project <br />is feasible, necessary and cost - effective (as Chapter 429 requires), does that constitute a <br />staff recommendation of no utilities? What if the recommendation is qualified in some <br />way? If those hurdles are overcome, when is the street "completed" and what constitutes <br />"installation" of utilities" for purposes of measuring the five -year waiting period? Taken <br />together, these difficulties render this subdivision unenforceable as a practical matter. <br />Further, the opening sentence of the subdivision is another example of editorial <br />commentary that is not appropriate in a charter. The charter is a form of legislation, and <br />comments or explanation should be reserved for background materials <br />327632v3 SJB LN140 -86 <br />